The
past three years have seen major changes in India 's
economic policies marking a new phase in India 's development strategy. The
broad thrust of the new policies is not very different from the changes being implemented
in other developing countries and also all over the erstwhile socialist world.
They aim at reducing the extent of Government controls over various aspects of
the domestic economy, increasing the role of the private sector, redirecting
scarce public sector resources to areas where the private sector is unlikely to
enter, and opening up the economy to trade and foreign investment.
These
changes have been accompanied by a lively debate in India and have also attracted
interest abroad. International opinion has typically welcomed the reforms and
generally urged a much faster pace of implementation, especially in view of
changes taking place in other countries. Within India , opinion has been more
varied. There are some who question the very direction of reform, but this is
definitely a minority opinion. More generally, the broad direction of reform
has met with wide approval, but there are differences of view on what should be
the pace and sequencing of reforms. While there is widespread support for the
elimination of bureaucratic controls over domestic producers, there are
differences on such issues as the speed at which protection to domestic
industry should be reduced, the extent to which domestic industry can be
subjected to foreign competition without being freed from the currently
prevalent rigidities in the domestic labour market; the extent to which
privatisation should be pursued etc. These are obviously critical issues in
designing a reform programme. They become particularly important when all the
elements of an optimal package cannot be fully implemented simultaneously owing
to social or political constraints. This confronts reformers with typical
"second best" problems since the infeasibility of one element of the
package could make pursuit of other elements anfractuous even counter-
productive. The recently developed literature on the sequencing of reform in
developing countries provides some guidance in making these difficult choices
though it is far from being conclusive.
This
paper presents an overview of what has been achieved in India 's current
reforms. It indicates some of the compulsions affecting the sequencing and pace
of reforms and attempts to evaluate the internal consistency of the resulting
package. The paper also presents a tentative assessment of the results achieved
at the end of the third year.
I. A Gradualist
Approach
An
important feature of India 's
reform programme, when compared with reforms underway in many other countries,
is that it has emphasised gradualism and evolutionary transition rather than
rapid restructuring or "shock therapy". This gradualism has often
been the subject of unfavourable comment by the more impatient advocates of
reform both inside and outside the country. Before considering the contents and
design of the Indian reform programme, it is useful to review some of the main
reasons why India 's
reforms have followed a gradualist path.
One
reason for gradualism is simply that the reforms were not introduced in the
background of a prolonged economic crisis or system collapse of the type which
would have created a widespread desire for, and willingness to accept, radical
restructuring. The reforms were introduced in June 1991 in the wake a balance
of payments crisis which was certainly severe. However, it was not a prolonged
crisis with a long period of non-performance. On the contrary, the crisis
erupted suddenly at the end of a period of apparently healthy growth in the
1980s, when the Indian economy grew at about 5.5% per year on average. This may
appear modest by East Asian standards, but it was much better than India 's
previous experience of 3.5 to 4% growth and was also better than the average
growth rate of all developing countries taken together in the same period.
Not
only did economic performance improve in the eighties, this improvement was
itself perceived to be the result of a process of evolutionary reform. By the
beginning of the decade of the eighties it began to be recognised that the
system of controls, with a heavy dependence on the public sector and a highly
protected inward oriented type of industrialisation, could not deliver rapid
growth in an increasingly competitive world environment. The sustained superior
performance of East Asian countries was evident to all by the mid-eighties, and
this helped create a perception that India could and should do better,
but the approach remained one of evolutionary change. Several initiatives were
taken in the second half of eighties to mitigate the rigours of the control
regime, lower direct tax rates, expand the role of the private sector, and
liberalise licensing controls on both trade and foreign investment. However,
these changes were marginal rather than fundamental in nature amounting more to
loosening controls and operating them more flexibly rather than a comprehensive
shift away from a regime of controls. Since the economy was seen to have
responded well to these initiatives, with an acceleration in growth in the
1980s, it created a strong presumption in favour of evolutionary change.
Finally,
gradualism was the inevitable outcome of India 's democratic and highly
pluralistic polity in which economic reforms can be implemented only if they
are based on a sufficiently wide popular consensus. The favourable experience
of liberalisation in the 1980s had created an intellectual climate for
continuing in the same direction, and the crisis of 1991 certainly
"concentrated the mind" in favour of bolder reforms, but the pace of
reforms had to be calibrated to what would be acceptable in a democratic
polity.[2]
This consideration was all the more important in June 1991 since the new
Government did not at that time have a majority in Parliament.
II. The Scope and
Coverage of the Reforms
The
reform programme initiated in June 1991, though gradualist in its approach, was
nevertheless very different from the incremental approach to reforms of the
1980s. As far as objectives are concerned, the current reforms are based on a
much clearer recognition of the need to integrate with the global economy
through trade, investment and technology flows and for this purpose to create
conditions which would give Indian entrepreneurs an environment broadly
comparable to that in other developing countries, and to do this within the
space of four to five years. As far as instruments are concerned, there is
clear recognition that the reforms cannot be limited to piecemeal adjustments
in one or other aspect of policy but must bring about system changes affecting
several sectors of the economy. The comprehensiveness of the reforms was not
perhaps fully evident at the very beginning, when the primary focus was on
restoring macro-economic stability, but as the reforms proceeded the scope and
coverage of the reform effort was more clearly outlined. The main elements of
the reform are summarised in this section, which also indicates differences in
the pace and sequencing of individual elements in the package.
i) Fiscal
Stabilisation
If
the recent literature on sequencing of reforms yields one firm conclusion it is
that fiscal stabilisation is an essential precondition for the success of
economic reforms. The design of India 's
reform programme was fully in line with this conclusion and fiscal
stabilisation was given the highest priority, especially in the initial phase
of crisis management when the current account deficit was high and inflation in
double digits.
The
Central Government fiscal deficit had expanded steadily during the eighties and
had reached a peak level of 8.4% of GDP
in 1990-91. Allowing for deficits of the State Governments, this meant an
overall Government fiscal deficit of around 10% which is high by any standard.
A reduction in the Central Government's fiscal deficit was therefore critical
for the reforms to take off. The first year of the reforms saw a substantial
reduction in the Central Government fiscal deficit from 8.4% of the GDP in 1990-91 to 5.9% in 1991-92 and further to
5.7% in 1992-93. Some of the reduction in the fiscal deficit in the first two
years was achieved by systemic improvements which permanently strengthened the
fiscal situation, such as for example the abolition of export subsidies in
1991-92 and the partial restructuring of fertiliser subsidy in 1992-93. Another
important systems change was the announcement that budget support to loss
making public sector units in the form of Government loans to cover their
losses would be progressively phased out. However part of the fiscal adjustment
in the first two years was also achieved by restricting development
expenditure, including expenditure on social and economic infrastructure.
Despite this limitation, the success achieved in fiscal consolidation in the
first two years was commendable, with the fiscal deficit being reduced by 2.7
percentage points of GDP . In this
respect the management of reforms in the first two years was entirely in line
with the prevailing consensus on sequencing.
The
process of fiscal consolidation was to continue into the third year of the
reform with the fiscal deficit expected to be reduced to 4.6% of GDP in 1993-94. In the event, there was a
substantial slippage from this target and the fiscal deficit in 1993-94 is
estimated at 7.3% of GDP . Part of
the slippage (about 1 percentage point of GDP )
was due to a shortfall in tax revenues compared to Budget targets. Customs
revenues were substantially below the target because imports were much lower
than expected, despite significant reductions in customs duty rates and
liberalisation of imports implemented as part of the structural reform (see
below). Excise duty collections also fell short because industrial production
did not recover as rapidly as expected. The rest of the slippage (about 1.7
percentage points of GDP ) was due
to expenditures exceeding targets. Delays in adjusting food prices in the
public distribution system led to higher food subsidy and expenditures on
development were higher than projected partly because of larger flows of
resources to support development expenditure of the States. To some extent the
overshooting of expenditures reflects pent up pressures, which had built up
over two years of fiscal consolidation and were difficult to resist.
It
is also true that the overshooting of expenditure in 1993-94 was to some extent
tolerated in 1993-94 because the economy was suffering from underutilisation of
capacity. Public sector investment, especially by the States, was held back by
fiscal constraints and private sector investment was also restrained as the
corporate sector re-adjusted its investment plans in line with the new, much
more competitive economic environment. The prevalence of excess capacity in
parts of the economy, combined with a surprisingly easy external payments
position, and a sharp reduction in inflation to less than 6% in mid-1993 led to
a willingness to accept a more expansionary fiscal policy.
The
unexpected increase in the fiscal deficit in 1993- 94 is understandably a cause
of considerable concern among observers of the reform programme. Experience in
many developing countries provides several examples of reform efforts which
have been aborted by premature easing of fiscal control. The Government has
recognised this problem and has indicated that the deviation from the path of
fiscal consolidation in 1993-94 was a temporary phenomenon and will be reversed
in 1994-95. Accordingly, the target for the fiscal deficit in 1994-95 has been
set at 6 per cent of GDP , which is
a significant improvement over the actual performance in 1993-94.
An
important new initiative in the 1994-95 Budget is the announcement that there
will be a pre-determined cap on the extent of monetisation of the Government
deficit which did not exist earlier since the Government could borrow from the
Reserve Bank without limit. It is now proposed to operate a ceiling on
Government borrowing from the Reserve Bank by authorising the Reserve Bank to
auction Treasury Bills at market rates whenever the pre-determined ceiling is
breached for more than a specified period.
ii) Industrial Policy
and Foreign Investment
Perhaps
the most radical changes implemented in the reform package have been in the
area of Industrial Policy removing several barriers to entry in the earlier
environment. The system of pervasive industrial licensing prevalent earlier,
which required Government permission for new investments as well as for
substantial expansion of existing capacity, has been virtually abolished.
Licensing is now needed only for a small list of industries, most of which
remain subject to licensing primarily because of environmental and pollution
considerations. The parallel but separate controls over investment and
expansion by large industrial houses through the Monopolies and Restrictive
Trade Practices (MRTP) Act have also been eliminated. The many inefficiencies
of this system - carefully documented by Bhagwati and Desai as early as 1970 -
are now truly a part of history as far as the Central Government is concerned.
A comprehensive restructuring of the Companies Act is also underway which aims
at simplifying and modernising this aspect of the legal framework governing the
corporate sector.
One
area where licensing controls remain in place relates to the list of industries
reserved for the small scale sector. Doubts are often expressed on whether
reservation, which prevents larger units from entering the reserved areas to
compete with small scale industries, is a desirable instrument for promoting
the small scale sector. However the Government has indicated that the general
policy of reserving certain items for the small scale sector will continue for
social reasons. This restriction may not be very significant in practice since
the areas reserved in this way are actually quite small. The major problem
really arises in certain product areas which are reserved for the small scale
sector but which also have a substantial export potential such as for example
toys and "garments. In order to introduce a measure of flexibility in such
cases, the Government has modified policy to allow medium scale units to enter
such areas provided they export at least 50% of production.
The
list of industries reserved for the public sector has been drastically pruned
and many critical areas have been opened up to private sector participation.
Electric power generation has been opened up for private investment, including
foreign investment, and several State Governments are actively negotiating with
various foreign investors for establishing private sector power plants. The
hydrocarbon sector, covering petroleum exploration, production and refining has
also been opened up to the private sector including foreign investment and has
attracted significant investor interest. Air transport, which until recently
was a public sector monopoly, has been opened up to the private sector and some
new entrants have begun operations. The Telecommunication sector has also been
opened up for certain services such as cellular telephones, though the
modalities for inducting private sector participants have yet to be worked out.
The
liberalisation of controls over domestic investors has been accompanied by a
radical restructuring of the policy towards foreign investment. Earlier, India 's policy
towards foreign investment was selective and was widely perceived by foreign
investors as being unfriendly. The percentage of equity allowed to foreign
investors was generally restricted to a maximum of 40%, except in certain high
technology areas, and foreign investment was generally discouraged in the
consumer goods sector unless accompanied by strong export commitments. The new
policy is much more actively supportive of foreign investment in a wide range
of activities. Permission is automatically granted for foreign equity
investment upto 51% in a large list of 34 industries. For proposals involving
foreign equity beyond 51%, or for investments in industries outside the list,
applications are processed by a high level Foreign Investment Promotion Board.
The Board has established a record of speedy clearance of applications and the
total volume of foreign equity approved in the first 24 months amounts to $3
billion. This compares with annual levels of approvals of only about $150
million only a few years earlier. Various restrictions earlier applied on the
operation of companies with foreign equity of 40% or more have been eliminated
by amendment of the Foreign Exchange Regulation Act and all companies
incorporated in India
are now treated alike, irrespective of the level of foreign equity.
iii) Trade and
Exchange Rate Policy
In
keeping with the objective of greater openness and outward orientation, trade
policy has been very substantially liberalised for all except final consumer
goods. The complex import control regime earlier applicable to imports of raw
materials, other inputs into production and capital goods has been virtually
dismantled. Today, all raw materials, other inputs and capital goods, can be
freely imported except for a relatively small negative list. Imports of
consumer goods remain restricted except for the limited windows of permissible
imports of such items by returning Indians and a limited facility for imports
of some consumer goods allowed against special import licenses which are given
to certain categories of exporters as an incentive. The exclusion of consumer
goods from trade liberalisation is an important restrictive element in trade
policy - and the Government has indicated that this too will be gradually
liberalised - but for all other sectors quantitative restrictions on imports
have been largely eliminated.
The
removal of quantitative restrictions on imports has been accompanied by a
gradual lowering of customs duties. India 's customs duties before the
reforms were very high, with the average rate of duty being as high as 100% and
very substantial variations around this average. The Government has made a
series of downward adjustments in customs duties in each of the four Budgets
since 1991. The peak rate of customs duty applicable to several items was over
200% in 1991. It has been lowered to 65% in 1994. Other customs duty rates
below the peak have also been lowered, especially the duties on capital goods.
The rate of customs duty on capital goods used to be as high as 90-100% in 1991
with concessional duty imports of capital goods available only to 100% export
oriented units. The duties on capital goods have now been lowered to a range
from 20% to 40%. Even with these reductions, India 's customs duty rates are
still too high and the Government has indicated that it will continue the
process of lowering tariffs over the next two years to reach levels comparable
with other developing countries.
Exchange
rate policy has gone through a series of transitional regimes since 1991,
leading to a total transformation at the end of three years. The reforms began
with a devaluation of about 24% in July 1991 in a situation in which extensive
trade restrictions were still in place. The devaluation was accompanied by an
abolition of export subsidies to help the fiscal position, and an offsetting
increase in export incentives in the form of special incentive licenses
(Eximscrips) given to exporters which could be used to import items which were
otherwise restricted. These licenses were freely tradeable and commanded a
premium in the market depending upon the excess demand for restricted imports.
The system was modified in March 1992 by the introduction of an explicit dual
exchange rate system simultaneously with the dismantling of licensing
restrictions on import of raw materials, other inputs into production and
capital goods. These items were made freely importable against foreign exchange
obtained from the market at a market determined floating exchange rate. Imports
of certain critical item's such as petroleum, essential drugs, fertiliser and
defence related imports were paid for by foreign exchange made available at the
fixed official rate, and the demand for foreign exchange at the official rate
to pay for these imports was met by requiring exporters to surrender 40% of
their export earnings at the official rate. The remaining 60% of export
earnings was available to finance all other imports, all other current
transactions and debt service payments, at the market rate. This dual exchange
rate system was again a shortlived transitional arrangement to a unified
floating rate which was announced in March 1993. After a year's experience with
the unified rate the Government, in March 1994, announced further liberalisation
of payment restrictions on current transactions and stated its intention of
moving to current account convertibility. Capital controls however remain in
place.
Thus
in the short space of two and a half years the trade and payments system has
moved from a fixed and typically overvalued, exchange rate operating in a
framework of substantial trade restrictions and export subsidies, to a market
determined exchange rate within a framework of considerable liberalisation on
the trade account and the elimination of current restrictions. The transition
is by no means complete, since consumer goods remain subject to quantitative
restriction and tariffs are still high, but the changes made thus far are
certainly substantial. The fact that they have been successfully managed has
created the confidence necessary for an easy transition through the remaining
stages.
The
continuation of controls on the capital account is broadly in line with the
current consensus in the literature on sequencing which holds that liberalisation
of the current account and an effective management of such a liberalised system
should precede libralisation of the capital account.
iv) Tax Reform
Reform
of the tax system has been an important element in the Government's reform
programme with major changes contemplated in both direct and indirect taxes.
The broad directions of tax reform have been spelt out in the Report of the
Taxation Reforms Committee (Chelliah Committee). The Committee has recommended
a move towards a simpler system of direct taxation with moderate rates and
fewer exemptions, a progressive reduction in the level as well as the range of
variation of customs duties and a rationalisation of the domestic excise taxes
on industrial production with a switch from specific to ad valorem rates, fewer
duty rates and a drastic reduction if not elimination of exemptions. Substantial
progress has been made in these directions in the four Budgets that have been
presented since the reforms began and this is best seen by considering the
cumulative changes that have taken place in each of the major areas of
taxation:
·
The
maximum marginal rate of personal income tax was 56% in June 1991. This has now
been reduced to 40%.
·
The
incentive structure for savings in the form of financial assets has been strengthened.
The Wealth Tax, which was earlier applicable to all personal assets, has been
modified to exempt all productive assets including financial assets such as
bank deposits, shares and other securities.
·
The
rates of corporate income tax, which were 51.75% for a publicly listed company
and 57.5% for a closely held company have been unified and reduced to 46%. All
these rates are inclusive of a 15% surcharge. Without the 15% surcharge the
rate of corporate tax would be 40% which is the same as the maximum marginal
rate on personal taxation.
·
Customs
duties, as noted above, have been significantly reduced over the past three
years and the Government has indicated that further reductions are expected to
be implemented in phases to bring the rates in line with those prevailing in
other developing countries.
·
Excise
duties on domestic manufactured goods were charged at varying rates on
different commodities, with most of the duties being specific rather than ad
valorem. There were also a large number of exemptions. A system of tax credit
for taxes paid on inputs called Modified Value Added Tax or MODVAT was in force
but excluded important sectors such as textiles and petroleum. Duty credit was
also not available on excise duty paid on capital goods at the time of
investment. The Budget presented in February 1994 has greatly simplified the
system, with the bulk of the taxes shifted to an ad valorem basis and the
number of exemptions greatly reduced. The coverage of the tax credit for taxes
paid on inputs has been extended to include petroleum and capital goods. The
number of excise duty rates has been reduced from 21 to 10. A start has also
been made in extending indirect taxation to a few services by imposing a 5% tax
on telephone bills, premium payments for general insurance and stock brokers'
commissions. The longer term objective of the Government is to move to a Value
Added Tax, but this is still a distant prospect since it involves integration
of the taxes on production, which under the Constitution are levied by the
Central Government, with taxes on sales which are levied by State Governments.
These
reforms in the tax system go a long way towards the objective of creating a
system which avoids economic distortions, and ensures adequate buoyancy of
revenues to support the task of fiscal consolidation. The changes in tax
structure will have to be accompanied by major improvements in tax
administration to realise the full potential of reforms in this sector. The
Government has indicated that this is high on its agenda.
v) Public Sector
Policy
Reform
of the public sector is a critical element in structural adjustment programmes
all over the world and is also included on India 's reform agenda. However,
this is an area where changes are being implemented slowly. Unlike the case in
many other countries, where public sector reform has involved explicit
programmes of outright privatisation of public sector units combined with
closures of unviable units, the approach adopted in the Indian reform programme
is more limited.
Instead
of outright privatisation the Government has initiated a limited process of
disinvestment of Government equity in public sector companies, with Government
retaining 51% of the equity and also management control. The disinvestment
helps provide non-inflationary resources for the Government Budget, without
adding to the fiscal deficit. However this is not the only objective. The
emergence of private shareholders in public sector units and trading of public
sector shares in the stock markets are both expected to make public sector
managements more sensitive to commercial profitability. This is especially so
since the Government has decided not to use budgetary resources to finance
public sector investment in industry. Public sector companies have been given a
clear signal that in future their investment plans must be financed either by
internal resource generation or by resources raised from the capital markets -
both alternatives being bound to encourage and reward efficiency and commercial
orientation. A number of public sector units have resorted to the capital
markets to raise resources to finance their investment plans and this trend is
certain to accelerate in future.
The
policy towards loss making public sector units is also cautious. The Government
has announced that budgetary support to finance losses will be phased out over
three years and this has had a salutary effect in confronting public sector
units with a hard budget constraint. This needs to be supplemented with a
policy for active restructuring of these units wherever it is possible to make
them economically viable, and with closure combined with adequate compensation
for labour where it is not. The Government has not ordered any closures on its
own initiative, but an objective process for determining whether a unit should
be closed or not has been initiated by amending the Sick Industrial Companies
Act (SICA) to bring sick public sector companies under the purview of the Board
for Industrial and Financial Reconstruction (BIFR) in the same way as private
sector companies are covered. Sick public sector companies (defined under the
law as companies which have completely eroded their net worth) are now
automatically referred to the BIFR which will then consider whether a consensus
can be evolved among the existing management (i.e. Government, creditors and
labour) for a viable restructuring package which may involve some voluntary
burden sharing by all parties - banks may offer to reschedule loans, workers to
accept partial retrenchment or wage freezes, Government may have to give up
taxes due etc. The Board can also consider revival packages involving induction
of new managers, with a fresh injection of capital. If no consensus can be
evolved for a revival package the BIFR is authorised to order closure of the
unit and liquidation of its assets. This is a lengthy process but it does
provide an objective means of exploring ways of reviving sick public sector
units, with closure as a credible ultimate threat in extreme cases.
vi) Financial Sector
Reform
The
reforms in the real sector aim at creating a new set of incentives which will
encourage reallocation of resources towards more efficient uses. This process
needs to be underpinned by a parallel process of financial sector reform which
will enable the financial sector to mobilise savings and allocate them in a
manner which supports the process of restructuring in the real economy. Several
initiatives have been taken in these areas covering both the banking system and
the capital markets.
As
far as banking system reform is concerned, the Government has announced a
package of reforms to be implemented over a three year period based on the
report of the Committee on the Financial System (Narasimham Committee). The
high reserve requirements applicable to banks in the form of the statutory
liquidity ratio (SLR ) and the cash
reserve ratio (CRR ) were
essentially designed to support Government borrowing at below market rates of
interest and constituted a hidden tax on financial intermediation. The Government
has announced that these high reserve requirements will be progressively
reduced, and the process has already begun. Parallel with the reduction in the
requirements for compulsory investments by banks in Government securities, the
interest rates on Government securities are increasingly market determined.
Interest rate regulation in the banking system is also being reduced and
rationalised. Earlier the Reserve Bank of India prescribed a number of
different interest rates on deposits of different maturities and also a large
number of prescribed lending rates for different sectors and classes of
borrowers. Deposit rates for different maturities have now been freed subject
only to a single ceiling. The proportion of deposits which banks can accept in
the form of Certificates of Deposits, which are completely free from interest
rate regulation, has been increased. On the lending side the number of
prescribed interest rates for different types of borrowers has been reduced
from six to three and it is proposed to move to an even simpler system with
only one concessional rate and a single floor rate for all other loans.
Prudential
norms relating to income recognition, provisioning and capital adequacy
applicable to banks, have been brought in line with Basle Committee standards
and these norms are being phased in gradually to be fully in force by March
1996. Combined with improved accounting practices and management information
systems in the banks, this is expected to yield a much better picture of the
true financial condition of the banks. This in turn will improve the quality of
lending and generate pressures for greater efficiency among borrowing units.
The absence of such pressures from the banking system in the past has been one
of the reasons for pervasive inefficiency in many sectors of the economy.
The
new norms reveal that the nationalised banks, which account for about 90% of
total deposits, have a much higher proportion of non-performing assets than was
earlier supposed. Full provisioning for these assets will inevitably lead to
substantial impairment of capital and this means the nationalised banks will
require extensive injection of fresh capital to meet the new capital adequacy
norms. The Government has announced a programme of contributing fresh capital
to the nationalised banks which involves a substantial burden on the Budget.
This is unavoidable, reflecting the real cost of past banking inadequacies.
However, in order to mitigate the impact on the Budget it is envisaged that the
relatively stronger nationalised banks with good balance sheets will mobilise
additional capital from the market by issuing new equity to the public. This
will dilute the present 100% Government ownership of these banks by bringing in
new private shareholders though Government equity will remain at least 51%. It
is expected that the induction of private shareholders will create an
environment in which these banks will pay much greater attention to the
commercial viability of their operations.
The
banking system is also being opened up to competition from new private banks
and several new banking licenses have been granted. Branches of foreign banks
have also been expanded to increase competition. All these policy changes will
be supported by improved supervision by the Reserve Bank of India and
strengthening of the management systems within the nationalised banks. The
Government has also set up special Debt Recovery Tribunal to help facilitate
recovery by banks from defaulting borrowers. The end result of these
initiatives should be a much more efficient banking system which would
support greater efficiency in the real sector.
Parallel
with efforts to reform the banking system the Government has also embarked on a
major reform of the capital market. During the eighties the capital market grew
remarkably in size, with a sharp increase in the volume of resources being
raised by the corporate sector in the form of corporate debt and new equity.
The size of the investing public also expanded considerably especially in the
form of subscribers to mutual funds. This quantitative expansion was not
however matched by necessary qualitative improvements. India 's stock
exchanges have shown considerable dynamism, but they remained inadequately
regulated and suffered from lack of transparency in trading practices.
Supervision was not up to the level required to ensure investor protection.
Several
important initiatives have been taken in the past two years to remedy these
deficiencies and raise standards to those prevailing in countries with well
functioning efficient capital markets. The requirement of Government permission
for companies issuing capital, as well as the system of Government control over
the pricing of new issues of equity by private companies, has been abolished
with the repeal of the Capital Issues Control Act in May 1992. Firms are now
free to issue capital and price new issues according to market conditions
subject only to guidelines aimed at effective disclosure of information
necessary for investor protection. The Securities and Exchange Board of India
(SEBI) has been established as an independent statutory authority for
regulating the stock exchanges and supervising the major players in the capital
markets (brokers, underwriters, merchant bankers, mutual funds, etc). The focus
is not on control and Government intervention but on establishing a framework
of regulation to ensure transparency of trading practices, speedy settlement
procedures, enforcement of prudential norms and full disclosure for investor
protection.
An
important initiative taken as part of the reforms is the opening up of the
capital market for portfolio investments. Indian companies have been allowed to
access international capital markets by issuing equity abroad through the
mechanism of Global Depository Receipts. Foreign institutional investors
managing pension funds or other broad based institutional funds have been
allowed to invest directly in the Indian capital markets. Favourable tax
treatment has been granted to such investments to encourage capital inflows
through these routes. These initiatives have come at a time when international
fund managers are diversifying their portfolios by investing in "emerging
capital markets" and India
has benefited from this trend along with other developing countries. It is
estimated that inflows from international equity issues by Indian companies in
1993-94 amounts to about $2.5 billion, while foreign institutional investors
have invested about $1.5 billion in the domestic capital markets.
vii) Reforms and the
Agricultural Sector
With
over 70 per cent of the population in rural areas, and most of them dependent
on agriculture, it follows that the strategy for economic reforms must address
the constraints on efficiency and production in the agricultural sector. Much
of what needs to be done in this area consists of effective implementation of
the basic strategy for agricultural development that has worked well in many
parts of the country and needs to be extended to other parts. This calls for
substantial investments in land and water management, supply of improved seeds,
an effective system for delivery of rural credit and of course security of
tenure. Many of these elements fall within the area of responsibility of State
Governments.
A
disturbing feature of recent trends in the agricultural sector is that
real investment in agriculture, both public and private, has been stagnant.
There is need for substantial increase in public investment in agriculture and
irrigation but this can only happen if resources available for investment with
the State Governments can be increased. Unfortunately, investible resources
with State Governments have been seriously eroded because of large increases in
unproductive current expenditure and the heavy burden of losses on the
provision of basic economic services in rural areas such as electric power and
irrigation. Top priority must be given to reducing these implicit subsidies
through rational pricing of both water and electricity and also better
management. The resources thus saved should be devoted to increased investment
in agriculture and related rural infrastructure.
One
dimension in which agriculture will be helped by the new policies is the
expected general eguilibrium impact of reduced protection to industry, which
should reduce the anti-agriculture bias of the earlier high protection regime.
The new regime not only makes agricultural exports more competitive at the new
exchange rate, it also stimulates the growth of the agro-processing industry,
with strong backward linkage to agriculture. A logical extension of the current
programme of reforms is the elimination of all restrictions on movement of
agricultural commodities both domestically (across States) and also for
exports. This has been accepted as an element of the economic reforms. All
Central Government restrictions on domestic trade have been removed though some
State Governments restrictions remain. Restrictions on agricultural exports
have also been reduced significantly though not as yet fully eliminated. Some
of the remaining restrictions, such as for example the restriction on exports
of pulses and coarse grains are not really binding in practice but have been
continued with an eye to avoiding any psychological pressure on prices.
A
major area where policy reforms can help agriculture is in the area of rural
credit. Poor banking practices, including especially laxness regarding loan
recovery, has greatly weakened the cooperative credit system and has also
weakened rural lending by the commercial banking system. The financial sector
reforms currently underway will address this problem through a combination of
rationalisation of interest rates to reduce the disincentive of unviable
lending rates which discourage rural lending, recapitalisation of banks and
restructuring of cooperative credit institutions.
viii) Labour Market
Reforms
A
commonly heard complaint from domestic as well as foreign investors is that
labour markets are unduly rigid. Indian labour laws provide a high degree of
protection to labour with retrenchment of labour and closure of an unviable
unit requiring prior permission of the State Government for units employing
more than 100 workers. Such permission is not always granted and this leads to
the complaint that Indian firms lack the flexibility they need to adapt to
changed economic circumstances. Spokesmen of domestic industry, and also
foreign investors, make the point that firms must have the ability to retrench
labour and to close down unviable units if necessary or else they will not be
able to compete effectively with the rest of the world in a more open economy.
This flexibility is also relevant if old firms, with a hangover of excess
labour, have to compete with new firms without this burden.
One
of the lessons from the literature on sequencing is that if some markets take
longer to adjust than others, it is important to begin with reforms in the
markets which adjust slowest. On this basis, reforms in the labour markets
should have top priority since labour market typically take longer to adjust.
However it is also important to recognise that reform of labour laws is a
politically sensitive issue. Any weakening of the labour laws is likely to
evoke fears of widespread unemployment and this is especially the case at the
early stages of the reforms when the beneficial effect of the new policies in
terms of more rapid growth of output and employment has yet to gain momentum.
There is recognition, even in official circles, that excessive rigidity in the
Labour Laws may not be in the interest of employment creation, but a consensus
on how to tackle this problem has yet to emerge.
In
any case, reform of labour laws must come after the creation of credible safety
nets to deal with the problems of displaced labour. A first step in this
direction has been taken by the creation of a National Renewal Fund which will
finance compensation payments to labour rendered redundant in the course of
public sector restructuring and closure of unviable units. It will also finance
retraining programmes to help redeploy such labour. Financing for the fund is
being provided from the Central Budget and resources have been obtained from
multilateral and bilateral aid donors in support of this activity.
Approximately 20,000 workers were laid off and paid compensation from the NRF
in 1992-93 and a similar number again in 1993-94. As the process of
restructuring public sector firms gains momentum the NRF will play a larger
role in years to come.
The
reforms described in the previous section clearly go beyond piecemeal
adjustments of one or other aspect of policy. The reforms are far reaching and
cover several sectors of the economy in a mutually re-inforcing fashion. It is
however too early to attempt a definitive assessment of their impact on the
economy. In some areas, such as for example in the financial sector, the
reforms are still in the initial stages of implementation. Even where progress
has been rapid, as for example in industrial deregulation and trade
liberalisation, there are unavoidable lags before the economy can respond,
especially where the total response depends upon investment and the resulting
creation of new capacity. Nevertheless, it is useful to assess the results
achieved in terms of economic performance in the first three years.
The
success in managing the short term crisis and stabilising the economy are
impressive. Inflation has been reduced from a peak of 17% in August 1991 to
about 8.5% within two and a half years. Foreign exchange reserves have
increased from $1.2 billion in June 1991 to over $15 billion in March 1994.
Exports have responded well to the new trade policy and the exchange rate
regime, and exports (measured in US dollars) have grown by about 21% in the
first ten months of 1993-94. International confidence has been restored and there
is an upsurge of investor interest in India both for direct foreign
investments and also for portfolio investment.
The
results in terms of the medium term objectives of stimulating growth and
investment are less dramatic at this stage, but this is not altogether
surprising. Many countries going through structural adjustment have experienced
sluggish, and indeed even negative, growth in the early years. India 's
experience of structural adjustment has been much less painful. GDP growth dropped to 1.1% in 1991-92, which was
the first year of the reform, but it recovered to about 4% in 1992-93 and is
expected to continue at about the same rate in 1993-94. Growth has not
collapsed, but it is also true that the economy has not yet recovered to its
previous trend performance of 5.5% growth in the 1980s. Even the growth
achieved in 1992-93 and 1993-94 is largely on account of a good performance in
agriculture and the tertiary sector.
Industrial
growth, which is the main target of industrial and trade reforms, remained
sluggish at 1.8% in 1992-93 and is unlikely to exceed 3.5% in 1993-94. A
slowdown in industrial growth in the initial phase of economic reform was not
unexpected as Indian industry adjusted to the new competitive environment.
However, the success of the reforms will inevitably be measured by how quickly
the system returns to the earlier levels of 7 to 8% growth in industry. In fact
the medium term objective should be to accelerate quickly beyond this level. If
the aim of the reforms is to enable the economy to achieve growth rates of GDP of 6 to 7% in a sustainable manner this can
only be achieved if the industrial sector grows by about 10%.
The
transition to a higher and growth path for the economy, and one which is
sustainable from the balance of payments point of view, requires a revival in
total investment. The first two years of the reforms saw a slight decline in
the rate of investment (Gross Fixed Capital Formation as a per cent of GDP ) from 22.8% in 1990-91 to 21.3% in 1992-93.
National accounts data for 1993-94 are not yet available, but the rate of
investment is unlikely to have increased. Public investment has been low
because of severe resource constraints affecting State Governments. Private
investment has also been depressed as the corporate sector re-orients its
investment strategy to the new economic environment with greater domestic
competition and lower protection. Such reductions in the rate of investment
have occurred in other countries going through structural adjustment. To some extent
the lower rate of investment may be offset by greater efficiency in capital
use, and indeed this is a critical objective of much of the structural reforms.
However a revival of economic growth to levels above the 5.5% achieved in the
1980s will definitely call for higher rates of investment in the years ahead.
There
is evidence that private investment activity is beginning to revive and the new
investment will be more efficient. Corporate strategies are being re-oriented
to enable companies to perform effectively in the emerging, more competitive
environment. Firms are paying much more attention to modernisation of existing
plants than to creation of new capacity in greenfield sites, and this is a desirable
development since such investments are more cost effective. Several companies
are also undertaking labour rationalisation through voluntary retirement
schemes to ready themselves for stiffer competition. Financial sector reforms,
including especially the efforts being made to strengthen capital markets, are
creating an environment in which firms with a good track record and market
appeal are able to raise substantial volumes of capital both domestically and
internationally to finance modernisation and expansion. Increased interest by
foreign investors looking for joint venture partners is also helping to
stimulate investment optimism on the part of domestic firms through tie ups
with global partners.
The
revival of private investment will also need to be supported by higher level of
public investment in critical infrastructure areas such as power, railways,
roads, ports and irrigation. The new policies allow, and indeed encourage,
private investment in critical areas such as power and petroleum exploration,
and a limited beginning is also being made to induct private investment in
roads and ports. Telecommunication is another area where new initiation are
under consideration. However the quantitative significance of private
investment in these areas is bound to be modest initially and can only
supplement the public sector effort. The ability of the public sector to
undertake the large investments needed in the medium term is therefore critical
for the success of the reforms. This will in turn depend upon improved
financial performance of major public sector organisations such as the State
Electricity Boards and also an improvement in the fiscal position of both the
Central and State Governments.
Improvement
in the fiscal position of the Central and State Government is important not
only to bring about a revival of investment in infrastructural but more
generally for creating a favourable macro-economic environment in which the
reforms can operate. Successful management of a liberalised and more open
economy, with increasing liberalisation of the financial sector, depends
crucially upon the fiscal deficit being reduced substantially from present
levels. This is a key element of the current strategy and as long as progress
in this dimension continues, there is good reason to expect that the reforms
launched in 1991 will succeed in shifting the Indian economy on to a higher
growth path.
-Montek S Ahluwalia*
No comments:
Post a Comment